"Is the Feds Game Worth the Candle?"
By: Gregory D. CurtisPosted on February 20, 2013 http://gregorydcurtis.com/ Topics:
Introduced by Dr. John A. Baden, PhD
Here is one great truth that has stuck with me since I was an undergraduate. There is little disagreement among micro economists; their basic model is largely uncontested. This field studies the behavior of individual households and firms in making decisions on the allocation of limited resources. It examines markets and political systems where goods or services are bought and sold. Microeconomics explores how these decisions and behaviors affect the supply and demand for goods and services. It focuses on opportunity costs and how prices, monetary and political, determine the quantity and quality supplied and demanded. This agreement is independent of economists' preferences for policy outcomes. Conservative, libertarian, and progressive economists generally agree on the framework of their analysis.
I detected a great contrast among macro economists. Really smart individuals who devoted their professional lives to this field held no such consensus. They have wide and unsettled disagreements on multiple dimensions. Yet, macroeconomics is fundamentally important to our and other nations. It examines the context within which decisions occur.
I've focused on the application of microeconomics to issues of public policy. My colleagues and I have applied public choice, a field of microeconomics, to issues of natural resource management. This approach is centered in Bozeman and evolved into the New Resource Economics, the NRE. (It's more popularly known as Free Market Environmentalism, or FME.) Bozeman is the ideal and obvious place for this work. Location matters.
Still, our analysis of the national parks, forests, range lands, waters, and wildlife occurs in a far broader setting, that of macroeconomics. This is beyond my work. In this arena I'm only a naive consumer, not a producer. Hence, I appreciate clear expositions of its underlying forces and operations.
A year ago a friend, Bob Cindrich, a retired federal who participated in several FREE programs, sent me an enlightening white paper, "Why We May Be Living in a Permanent Financial Crisis". It is by Gregory Curtis, Chm. of Greycourt & Company, a well-respected investment firm in Pittsburg, PA. Mr. Curtis studied economics at Dartmouth and earned a law degree from Harvard. I was greatly impressed with his paper and asked to receive his further work. Here is his latest, "Is the Feds Game Worth the Candle." I find it helpful and with his permission am sharing it with you. This is from the beginning:
"...the Fed has over-estimated its understanding of and ability to stimulate the American economy. I then argued that the last resort for the Fed – that the “wealth effect” would pull the US out of its slump – was a crock."
Read on! http://gregorydcurtis.com/is-the-feds-game-worth-the-candle/
Is the Fed’s Game Worth the Candle?
Posted February 14, 2013 by gcurtis & filed under Uncategorized.
A blog is really nothing more than the process of jotting down stuff you’re thinking about when you should really be doing something else. This probably explains why so many more people are addicted to blogging than are addicted to reading blogs. Right now, for example, I should be slogging through Greycourt’s year-end financial statements. Instead, I’m still thinking about Ben Bernanke.
In my last two posts I argued, first, that the Fed has over-estimated its understanding of and ability to stimulate the American economy. I then argued that the last resort for the Fed – that the “wealth effect” would pull the US out of its slump – was a crock.
But people often say to me, “Hey, at least the Fed is trying to do something, which is more than you can say for Congress.” True enough, and if the risks that the Fed’s unprecedented policy initiatives presented to the economy were low, well, why not? But suppose those risks are high? Suppose they are extreme? A do-nothing Congress starts to sound better and better. The US economy is a highly resilient animal, and if you don’t do something to screw it up it will likely turn out just fine.
Is the Fed doing something that’s screwing up the US economy? Many people who are a lot smarter than me think the Fed’s (and other central bankers’) policy experiments are risky. I won’t repeat all the risks here (see, among many others, but for particularly blood-curdling fun, Jeremy Grantham’s Night of the Living Fed, here.)
Instead, I’ll simply mention the three concerns that keep me up at night, which are, in no particular order:
Groupthink. Following the Crash of ’29 and the subsequent economic collapse, central bankers and chancellors of the exchequer all over the world thought they knew exactly what to do to set the world right. Since the problems had been caused (in their view) by rank speculation and a serious departure from the old habits of thrift, the world’s economies could easily be righted by proceeding as follows (I’m using words attributed to US Treasury Secretary Andrew W. Mellon):
“Liquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate farmers, liquidate real estate… it will purge the rottenness out of the system. High costs of living and high living will come down. People will work harder, live a more moral life. Values will be adjusted, and enterprising people will pick up from less competent people.”(1)
As we now know, all the central bankers and all the chancellors of the exchequer were flat-out wrong. Whatever the causes of the crisis of the 1930s, the solution wasn’t to starve the plunging economies of capital, but to make capital more available so the world could pull itself out of its downward spiral. This was the core insight of economists who studied the Great Depression, including, of course, Ben Bernanke.
Fast forward roughly eighty years and we have Groupthink 2.0. Every central banker in the world and every chancellor of the exchequer now believes the exact opposite of what their predecessors thought back in the Thirties: namely, that the way to deal with an economic crisis is to stimulate, stimulate, stimulate, and when you’ve finished stimulating, stimulate some more. (2)
Has it occurred to anyone that there’s a middle ground here?
Iniquitousness. I know, I’m starting to sound positively Biblical. But has anyone noticed that central banker policies actively discourage actions we would think of as desirable in a citizenry, and encourage actions we would think of as undesirable? Is this the way powerful government officials ought to behave?
Millions of people in the US and across the world played the Game of Life straight up, saving their money for their retirements, postponing gratification. Millions of these and other people focus on risk when thinking about their investment portfolios, never taking on more risk than they are comfortable with, never “reaching for yield.”
Central bankers sneer at such people. They are, in the (adapted) words of Secretary Mellon, to be “liquidated.” What the central bankers celebrate are speculators and folks who reach for yield at any cost. And this is supposed to be our salvation?
Dismal scientists like to worry about the so-called “paradox of thrift:” when times get tough, people save more, causing times to get tougher. No doubt it’s true, at least in a small way. (3) But every problem in the world doesn’t have a solution that isn’t worse than the problem itself. I could swear, for example, remembering Mom say that two wrongs don’t make a right. Undermining public and private virtue because economic theory says we should is no way to run a railroad.
Enabling. Imagine we wake up one morning to discover that our teenage daughter is mainlining heroin. One possible response would be to stock up on the drug so the girl wouldn’t run out of it while she’s figuring out how to kick the habit. Well, yes, that’s one possible response, but most of us would consider it so completely idiotic that we would have to wonder why someone would mention it in his blog.
The reason I mention it, of course, is that it precisely describes the actions of the world’s central bankers. They all woke up one morning and discovered that the world’s developed economies were mainlining debt, entitlements, and low tax rates. “Aha!” they cried. “What we’ll do is give them a big dose of… more debt, more entitlements, more low tax rates!” (Except for taxing the rich, of course, since that doesn’t raise any money.)
Instead, I suggest the Federal Reserve place the following letter in the overnight express.
Dear Boys & Girls of the US Congress:
We admit that we’ve been bad, enabling central bankers for ‘lo these many years. But we’ve seen the error of our ways.
Effective immediately, we will take the following actions:
1. Beginning this week, we will cease to reinvest principal payments on our portfolio of mortgage and Treasury securities.
2. In six months we will stop buying $85 billion of securities every month and will start raising the federal funds target rate.
3. In one year we will begin selling off our $3 trillion balance sheet.
Yes, these actions will likely cause the stock market to crash and the economy to plunge into recession. But these are trivial
issues compared with the headlong rush to catastrophe we’ve been enabling. You have roughly one year to come to grips with
our problems of debt, entitlements, and revenue. After that, you will probably all be recalled.
Hugs & kisses,
The Fed
(1) Actually, the only evidence that Mellon ever said anything of the sort comes from Herbert Hoover’s autobiography, conveniently published seventeen years after Mellon died.
(2) Not to sound like a conspiracy theorist, but Ben Bernanke, Mario Draghi, and all four (!) division heads at the Fed have Ph.D.s from MIT. Prime Minister Abe, desperate to avoid having to take any action himself to resolve Japan’s deep, structural problems, is probably in Kendall Square right now scouting around for a stimulator.
(3) Actually, though, in the real world some people don’t save more no matter what (the rich), and some people don’t save more no matter what (the poor), and some people don’t save more no matter what (the clueless), leaving, precisely, who?